Escalating electric power demand from artificial intelligence (AI) has prompted a range of media, political, and regulatory responses including congressional hearings, state policy actions, and increased focus in energy forums. Experts and policymakers have been especially concerned that power-hungry AI may erode grid reliability, raise energy costs for everyone, and skyrocket emissions. Further concerns, including those of presidential candidates, have surfaced that the inability to meet AI energy demand domestically poses strategic risks, as data centers might relocate offshore.  

This makes a snapshot of policy implications imperative. While initial analyses are in, the true extent of AI’s impact on energy systems remains highly uncertain. Analyses are often outdated within months of publication, with rapid revisions evident in demand-forecasting assumptions. Forecasts themselves are often questioned due to inherent regulatory incentives to inflate them. But enough is known to begin to profile AI’s energy and environmental footprint and frame a productive legislative and regulatory response. In short, while AI’s energy profile does not seem to present major economic or environmental concerns in a healthy marketplace, it amplifies the preexisting case to fix flawed public policy. 

Industry Background

To understand the effects of AI on electricity costs and reliability, it is important to understand how new demand affects electric infrastructure and operations. Generally, electric infrastructure is sized to meet peak demand and operates with large reserves the vast majority of the time. For example, half of congestion costs on transmission lines came during only 5 percent of hours in recent years. Similarly, ample generation is available most any time, which is why generation adequacy concerns are commonly assessed for extreme weather in the top 10th percentile. Put another way, on most days, less than half of available infrastructure and capacity is needed to meet demand. This is why the shape of new demand—especially whether it is flexible on-peak—carries more infrastructure implications than its overall consumption volume. 

The location of new demand also carries major infrastructure implications. Transmission and distribution systems have flow limitations, while generation is becoming more geographically dependent. All this results in high spatial variance in the cost to serve new demand. In fact, limitations on the transmission system to export power from generation-rich areas (such as windy areas) increasingly require grid operators to curtail power production even if doing so would improve reliability and lower cost elsewhere on the system. Consequently, there is slack on the power system the vast majority of the time, especially in certain locations. At the same time, certain locations face persistently tight supply-demand conditions because of chronically saturated infrastructure. 

As such, the size, shape, and location of AI’s energy profile has major bearings on its electric cost and reliability implications. It turns out that the same characteristics profoundly affect its emissions profile as well. That is, the emissions of marginal power demand fluctuates by multiples depending on location and real-time supply-demand balance on the grid. In short, the more flexible AI is in operating and siting new data centers, the lower its environmental footprint and strain on electric infrastructure. 

The regulatory paradigm influences the location and flexibility of power demand as well as the speed, cost, emissions, and risk profile of new supply infrastructure. States with competitive wholesale and retail electric markets harness competitive forces to drive generation decisions. Markets provide granular temporal and spatial price signals to incent demand to locate and operate flexibly. States with traditional cost-of-service regulation lack these incentives because the monopoly utility’s financial motive is to expand the asset base upon which it earns a regulated return. 

Transmission and distribution (T&D) infrastructure is mostly on cost-of-service regulation. T&D regulatory architecture—including variances in planning transparency, use of cost-benefit analysis, competitive bidding, and other features that affect the economic performance of T&D expansion—varies by region and state. All categories of power infrastructure face growing permitting and siting challenges, which are especially problematic in an era of resurgent load growth. 

The mesh point of regulatory architecture with AI’s energy profile shapes the cost, reliability, and environmental implications of AI energy needs. A peer lesson comes from cryptocurrency, which is extremely flexible in its siting and operational profile. Crypto miners increasingly locate in renewables-rich areas of states with competitive electricity markets, consume when supplies are ample, and curtail their power consumption when grid conditions tighten. Thus, despite a boom in power consumption, crypto mining has resulted in low incremental infrastructure and emissions impact. This would not be the case with inflexible demand growth in monopoly utility footprints. 

AI’s Energy Profile

Figure 1

Source: Chart created from R Street analysis of Brattle Group data 

A series of reports and conversations shed light on AI’s emerging energy profile. Key profile characteristics include demand size, location, shape, and reliability and environmental preferences.

Observed trends and expected conditions leave us with six takeaways from AI’s energy profile: 

Policy Implications

AI’s energy profile underscores the value of free and competitive markets. States with competitive electricity markets and low permitting barriers should outperform on economic, reliability, and environmental grounds. Aside from Texas, however, nearly all states have unnecessary monopoly utilities and/or restrictive permitting practices. Federal permitting reforms have momentum, but state permitting restrictions have grown sharply throughout the past decade, threatening the retention of economical existing infrastructure and the expansion of new facilities. New power plants in most regions face five-year wait times just to receive approval to interconnect to the regional grid. 

To a degree, competitive electricity markets are incenting new demand, including AI, to locate where there is infrastructure slack, to operate more flexibly, and to adopt on-site generation. Most prominently, tech firms are collaborating with competitive power plant owners to build out data centers at the site of nuclear plants. This development, known as “co-location,” is a welcome sign of market creativity. In addition to nuclear co-location, high wind-producing areas routinely have surpluses of local, emissions-free generation that attracts data center development. Such practices reduce infrastructure burdens and lower per-unit emissions from data center expansion. This explains why large consumers, including data centers, seek reforms to give consumers direct market access in these areas. 

By contrast, monopoly utilities have a track record of suppressing demand flexibility, on-site generation, and incentives to locate demand where it is least burdensome to infrastructure. It is little surprise, then, that monopolies are slow to adapt to AI’s energy needs, even denying service unless data centers pay new rates. Distribution and local transmission investments are made exclusively by monopoly utilities out of necessity, but grid upgrades for new data centers are overly slow and expensive given utility system opacity and the lack of least-cost investment analyses. 

Regression is a major concern in competitive states like Ohio and Pennsylvania, where distribution-service monopolies are vying for states to re-monopolize generation despite consumer opposition. This would force captive ratepayers to finance monopoly generation to meet new demand. Doing so would displace lower-cost generation from competitive suppliers and exacerbate system-wide investment risk. Such cross-subsidies fundamentally compromise the integrity of competitive markets

Distortive market interventions are often motivated by the perceived reliability risk that is amplified by demand growth. Yet markets are especially advantageous under high certainty, which is perhaps the single best characterization of AI energy demand. Competitive suppliers absorb risk and manage it well, whereas monopoly utilities socialize risk and have a track record of overbuilding supply and choosing overly expensive supply options. Markets also outperform when consumers have diverse preferences, and AI developers have unique preferences for service reliability and emissions avoidance. 

States with competitive electricity markets and consumer choice are easier for green-minded consumers—including AI developers—to contract for clean energy. This explains why Texas has become the country’s clean energy leader. Regions like the Mid-Atlantic that publish locational marginal emissions data make it possible to account for the indirect emissions from power consumption. Adopting this in Texas, for example, could double the carbon displacement of clean energy deployment. Despite green appetite from power consumers including AI, unclear and overreaching financial regulation has deterred suppliers from developing innovative products that best reduce the indirect emissions of power consumption. 

Several policy takeaways from AI’s energy growth: 

Subscribe to updates from our Energy and Environment policy team, including our Low-Energy Fridays newsletter.